News

May 2017 Positive Money New Zealand issued a press release seeking clarity from the Reserve Bank on how our money is created.  They still refer to intermediation by the banks, which is not how our banking system works.

5th November 2016 An article in The Guardian newspaper in England argued that abolishing debt-based currency holds the secret to getting our system off its addiction to growth.

5th September 2016 KPMG released a report, commissioned by the Prime Minister of Iceland, titled "Money Issuance" The report looked at money created by the Government.

28 March 2016 Bryan Gould has agreed to be the Patron for Positive Money New Zealand.

Bryan is a respected commentator on economic matters, an author, academic and Companion of the New Zealand Order of Merit.

31 October 2015 A monetary reform group in Switzerland has enough signatures for a referendum on who creates their money supply.

14 October 2015 The Finance Commission of the Dutch parliament discussed monetary reform.

31 March 2015. The Telegraph in London reports on the Icelandic governments plan to have their central bank issue their money supply and calls it a radical plan.

22 November. The British parliament debated money creation last week, for the first time in 170 years. There was cross-party support for a proposal to set up a monetary commission

23 September. A new generation of young people, dubbed ''property orphans'' may be destined to be renters for life.

17 September. The Bank of International Settlements (BIS), the bank used by central banks, confirmed New Zealand houses are among the most "unaffordable" in the world compared to people's incomes.

6 September. Bruce Bisset of Hawkes Bay today reveals the true story behind the so called Rock Star economy.

25th April 2014 "Strip private banks of their power to create money”: says the Financial Times’ chief economics commentator Martin Wolf, who endorses Positive Money’s proposals for reform

15th March 2014 - In a historic move The Bank of England quarterly bulletin explains how money is created. Whenever a bank makes a loan, it creates a deposit in the borrower’s bank account, thereby creating new money. The bank says that this differs from the story found in some economics textbooks.

16th August 2013. The retiring head of the Financial Markets Authority apologised for the mistakes made saying “You were let down”.

 

John Kenneth Galbraith“The study of money, above all other fields in economics, is one in which complexity is used to disguise truth or to evade truth, not to reveal it. The process by which banks create money is so simple the mind is repelled. With something so important, a deeper mystery seems only decent.”

John Kenneth Galbraith (1908-2006 ), former professor of economics at Harvard, writing in ‘Money: Whence it came, where it went’ (1975).

Investment Account Guarantees


Under the existing system, if a bank fails due to bad investments, a third party (the taxpayer) may be asked to reimburse the savers who have money invested with that bank. (This scheme is called deposit insurance.  New Zealand had a deposit insurance scheme during 2009 – 2010 which has lapsed.)

This creates a few serious flaws or 'distortions' in the economic system:

  1. It means that the banks can speculate with their customers' money in the knowledge that the government will probably step in to cover any serious losses. This creates 'moral hazard' and encourages the banks to take greater risks in their investments.
  2. It means that one group stands to benefit if the bank is successful in its investments, while another group (taxpayers) stands to lose if the bank is unsuccessful. If customers bear at least some of the risk of the investment, it should encourage them to be more vocal in how the banks invests their customers' money - maybe expressing concern that large sums of money go in to risky proprietary trading, or requesting accounts where the money is ring-fenced for certain types of investment.

Our proposal contains a few simple rules that collectively 'fix' these fundamental problems in the current design of the banking system. Practically, it works as follows:

  1. An institution has the option of offering Investment Account holders a guarantee that they will be repaid a minimum percentage of their original investment. For example, the bank may say that a particular Investment Account product guarantees to repay the investor at least 100%, or 80%, or 60%, of the amount originally invested.
  2. The institution may also offer a guarantee on the rate of interest that will be paid on the Investment Account product, for example, guaranteeing to pay 2%, 4% or 5% interest.

A worked example

Let's look at a worked example. Imagine that a bank wants to attract money to fund conservative housing market loans to middle-income families. It charges an interest rate of 8% on the mortgages, and it knows that only a tiny percentage of the loans that it makes to these middle-income families will actually default.

Consequently, allowing for defaults, the normal case rate-of-return will probably be around 7.8% overall (over all the funds invested in this type of mortgage), and in the very worst case scenario, with a high rate of defaults, the rate of return might drop to 2% (with the losses of the defaults being cancelled out by the interest paid by those who don't default).

Because the bank knows that, in the very worst case scenario it is still likely to make a return of 2%, then it knows that investing in this market is effectively 'risk free', in that it is highly unlikely to lose more than the bank originally invests.

Consequently, in order to attract more funds into its Investment Accounts in order to fund more lending in this particular market (i.e. mortgages for middle-income families), it may offer to guarantee the original sum invested, and guarantee a rate of return of 2%.

This makes this a 'risk-free' investment for the Investment Account holders, and provides a good alternative for savers/investors who don't want to take much risk and don't need a very high return.

In this situation, the bank holds all the risk of the investment. If the investments were made badly and the bank actually lost 20% of everything it invested, it would still need to repay the entire original sum to each Investment Account holders, plus 2% interest. It would then need to cover its losses with its own profits.  In other words, bad investments by the banks would wipe out their profits for the year (or the next few years, if they really miscalculated their investments).

Let's look at another scenario. Imagine that the bank wants to raise funds for investing in a risky, emerging market. The possible return here is much higher, but the risk of loss is much greater too.

The bank wants to limit its own risk by sharing some of the risk with customers. The potential interest rate that it will offer if its investments are successful is 8%. However, if it is unsuccessful, and the market turns out to be a bubble about to burst, it could end up losing up to 50% of the funds invested.

In this case, the bank may opt to offer no guarantee on the rate of return, and to offer a guarantee of 60% of the principal invested. This would attract funds but would force the investors to share the risk with the bank. If the investments failed badly, the investors would lose 40% of the principal, and the bank would need to make up the other 10% of the losses from its own profits.

Some of us may read the figures above and say that it is not 'fair' that the bank only risks 10% while the investors risk 40% of their  investment. However, in every case, each investor would have been made aware of the guarantees, and therefore made their own decision to invest in a particular Investment Account, knowing the risk to them and the potential upside.

These two 'guarantees' set up the conditions in which competition between the banks will lead them to offer a full range of products for every type of investor. Investors who want a high rate of return will need to take on some of the risk themselves, and investors who are happy with a low rate of return will be able to invest effectively risk-free.

No government guarantee on Investment Accounts

The Reserve Bank and government would not back the guarantees made by the banks. If a bank went bankrupt, Investment Account holders would become creditors of the bank and would have to wait for normal liquidation procedures to take place to see if they will get back part of their investment.

The Reserve Bank may forbid specific guarantees

We have allowed whichever institution that is charged with supervising the NZ banking system to forbid an institution from offering a particular rate of return on a particular Investment Account product. This provision is necessary to prevent banks from offering unrealistic guarantees.

We know from history that professionals in the financial sector are not very good at identifying bubbles while they are in one. When a bubble takes off in say, hotel construction, a bank has an incentive to offer a better guarantee than all its competitors in a particular Investment Account product in order to attract the maximum amount of funds for investment in the bubble.

The guarantee they offer may be one that is based on the 'best case scenario'.
If the bank tries to offer an Investment Account product with a guaranteed rate of return of 8%, the Reserve Bank may judge that it is highly likely that the investments themselves will not generate a return of 8%, and therefore the bank will end up with a shortfall, which will increase the likelihood of the bank going bankrupt or appealing to the Reserve Bank for emergency funding.

In short, offering a guarantee (on either the rate of return or the principal) which bears no relation to the real risks of the investment makes it more likely that the bank will run into financial difficulties, and therefore the Reserve Bank should be allowed to disallow any guarantee in order to maintain the stability of the banking system.

 

 

 

MoST Content Management V3.0.6374